1 00:00:06,740 --> 00:00:12,260 JEREMY: Hello and welcome to another episode of Eat This Podcast with me, Jeremy Cherfas. 2 00:00:13,640 --> 00:00:21,710 Last time we heard about the 3 billion people worldwide who cannot afford a healthy, nutritious diet. 3 00:00:21,890 --> 00:00:26,600 In this episode, a question that wasn't really relevant last time. 4 00:00:26,870 --> 00:00:31,100 When people do have more money, what kind of food do they actually buy? 5 00:00:32,330 --> 00:00:38,660 There's a lot of historical interest in this idea, going back at least to the middle of the 19th century. 6 00:00:38,660 --> 00:00:48,500 That's when Ernst Engels, a German statistician, published his discovery that as income goes up, the proportion spent 7 00:00:48,500 --> 00:00:53,150 on food goes down, even though the total amount spent on food goes up. 8 00:00:53,750 --> 00:01:03,640 That's now known as Engels Law, and an extension of Engels Law is called Bennett's Law, formulated by the American 9 00:01:03,640 --> 00:01:08,200 agricultural economist Merrill Bennett in 1941. 10 00:01:09,070 --> 00:01:17,920 MARC: Bennett's law is is the empirical regularity that says that as people go from very poor to less poor, they substitute away from coarse 11 00:01:17,920 --> 00:01:26,160 grains towards finer grains, so away from sorghum and millet and grains that are just filling, but not necessarily the tastiest, 12 00:01:26,160 --> 00:01:29,530 towards stuff like wheat, rice and corn. 13 00:01:29,920 --> 00:01:38,560 And as they go from merely poor to perhaps middle income or non-poor, they substitute away from carbohydrates altogether and start bringing 14 00:01:38,560 --> 00:01:42,160 in more protein, usually in the form of animal sourced foods. 15 00:01:42,700 --> 00:01:49,570 JEREMY: That's Mark Bellamere, also an agricultural economist and a frequent guest on this podcast. 16 00:01:49,600 --> 00:01:51,370 And did you catch what he said? 17 00:01:51,370 --> 00:01:57,490 That Bennett's law is not so much a law as an empirical regularity. 18 00:01:57,580 --> 00:02:05,830 What he means is that nobody had actually gone and accurately measured the kinds of foods that people buy when they have more money 19 00:02:05,830 --> 00:02:14,230 to spend, just that they notice that they do seem to switch from coarse grains to fine, and then from fine grains to protein. 20 00:02:14,440 --> 00:02:22,660 And of course, the reason I'm talking to Marc Bellemare about this now is that he and his colleagues have just published a paper in which 21 00:02:22,660 --> 00:02:29,500 they do actually measure what kinds of foods poor people buy when they have more to spend. 22 00:02:29,530 --> 00:02:34,720 It is, he says, the first credible test of Bennett's law. 23 00:02:35,230 --> 00:02:39,280 The point here is not that Bennett's law might be wrong. 24 00:02:39,280 --> 00:02:41,680 In fact, it's what you might expect. 25 00:02:41,680 --> 00:02:45,820 But nobody had actually looked in detail. 26 00:02:45,820 --> 00:02:48,880 MARC: On the basis of a handful of assumptions. 27 00:02:49,480 --> 00:02:55,990 Micro-theory will tell you that as income goes up, the demand for food goes up. 28 00:02:56,200 --> 00:03:01,260 So where we started from was, that is theory. 29 00:03:01,590 --> 00:03:03,120 What do we see empirically? 30 00:03:03,150 --> 00:03:04,740 Is that really true empirically? 31 00:03:04,740 --> 00:03:09,480 And can we get an answer to that question of what is the income elasticity of food demand? 32 00:03:09,480 --> 00:03:12,720 Because that's a very thorny issue, as you may know. 33 00:03:12,750 --> 00:03:13,230 And if you ... 34 00:03:13,260 --> 00:03:20,790 JEREMY: Let me just stop you for a minute there, because I understand price elasticity of demand. 35 00:03:20,790 --> 00:03:23,520 What is income elasticity of demand? 36 00:03:23,550 --> 00:03:31,860 MARC: The income elasticity of demand measures what happens to quantity demanded in percentage terms for a 1% increase in income. 37 00:03:31,860 --> 00:03:37,470 What's great about an elasticity measure, elasticity is a unit free unit of measurement. 38 00:03:37,470 --> 00:03:43,410 It tells you for a 1% change in something, how does the other thing respond in percentage terms. 39 00:03:43,410 --> 00:03:51,330 So it is -- whether you measure it in dollars, in euros in kwacha -- you get a measure that you can compare across contexts. 40 00:03:51,330 --> 00:03:54,210 And this is where we kind of come in with this paper because ... 41 00:03:54,300 --> 00:04:03,720 So we looked at what micro-theory says, we looked at what the empirical evidence so far said, and we asked ourselves, how can we do 42 00:04:03,720 --> 00:04:05,820 better? And it's fairly easy to do better. 43 00:04:05,850 --> 00:04:15,210 First off, you know, I take theory seriously, but I don't take it as gospel, meaning that economic theory is often wrong in specific 44 00:04:15,210 --> 00:04:21,000 contexts. It'll tell you one thing, and then you look at the data, you get the best estimate you can get, and you find something that is 45 00:04:21,000 --> 00:04:23,250 not in line with theory necessarily. 46 00:04:23,550 --> 00:04:33,090 But more worryingly for us, is the fact that many of the estimates you see in the literature that are bandied about by policy makers, 47 00:04:33,090 --> 00:04:40,170 some researchers, are just poorly identified, meaning that they are not necessarily an accurate number. 48 00:04:40,170 --> 00:04:43,050 And that is especially true when it comes to income elasticity of demand. 49 00:04:43,350 --> 00:04:44,910 That is something that I've taught. 50 00:04:44,910 --> 00:04:52,920 I think in most undergraduate courses I have ever taught, we don't really have a good sense of what happens to food demand when income 51 00:04:52,950 --> 00:04:58,330 goes up. The reason being the first thing is demand for what? 52 00:04:58,360 --> 00:05:02,020 Because you can measure the demand for food in several different ways. 53 00:05:02,710 --> 00:05:07,330 The most standard way that people think about would be perhaps in terms of calories, right? 54 00:05:07,360 --> 00:05:14,470 What we do in the paper is we look at food expenditures, because that is something that we can harmonize across contexts, and it is fairly 55 00:05:14,500 --> 00:05:15,910 accurately measurable. 56 00:05:15,940 --> 00:05:22,990 You know, I'm not saying that calories are not accurately measurable, but they're often based on imputations that are very old and that are 57 00:05:22,990 --> 00:05:28,840 dating to kind of a time when the calorie content of various foods was very different from what we have today. 58 00:05:29,260 --> 00:05:34,570 And so you can measure it in dollars or expenditures, you can measure it in calories. 59 00:05:34,930 --> 00:05:38,980 You can say we will measure it in terms of macronutrients. 60 00:05:39,040 --> 00:05:43,180 How many grams of protein, how many grams of carbohydrates do people consume? 61 00:05:43,690 --> 00:05:45,820 You can measure it in terms of micronutrients. 62 00:05:45,820 --> 00:05:49,510 You can say, well, what is the demand for vitamin A, vitamin D? 63 00:05:49,540 --> 00:05:58,360 And because we have so many different measurements of what food demand is, we have a construct validity issue, right? 64 00:05:58,390 --> 00:06:06,640 So me talking about food demand may not be the same thing as an FAO colleague talking about food demand or a nutritionist talking about 65 00:06:06,640 --> 00:06:09,670 food demand. We needed something that could be compared across contexts. 66 00:06:11,080 --> 00:06:16,840 And so we settled on food expenditures, which is by no means a perfect measure, but it is the measure that we have. 67 00:06:16,840 --> 00:06:20,260 It is something that is measurable in monetary terms. 68 00:06:20,260 --> 00:06:27,280 And then the way we got to writing this paper was, I recall having a conversation with Eeshani Kandpal, my co-author, one of my co-authors 69 00:06:27,280 --> 00:06:29,410 on this. The other is Katherina Thomas. 70 00:06:30,400 --> 00:06:39,190 And I remember telling her, I'm very interested in Bennett's Law because, you know, the name notwithstanding, it wasn't really a law up 71 00:06:39,190 --> 00:06:40,390 until our paper. 72 00:06:40,420 --> 00:06:46,390 Bennett's Law was more like, you know, something that we kind of observe in cross-sectional and time series data, but we don't really 73 00:06:46,390 --> 00:06:48,610 have an iron-clad estimate for. 74 00:06:49,000 --> 00:06:55,210 And so I recall an early conversation with Eeshani and saying, well, what could we work on together? 75 00:06:55,210 --> 00:06:59,520 And I said, well, we should do a randomized control trial where we test Bennett's Law. 76 00:06:59,520 --> 00:07:04,260 And Eeshani, who is infinitely smarter than I am, said, wait a second. 77 00:07:04,590 --> 00:07:06,750 We don't have to spend any money doing this. 78 00:07:06,750 --> 00:07:13,170 There are publicly available data sets of cash transfer, randomized controlled trials. 79 00:07:13,170 --> 00:07:15,480 So randomized trials where ... 80 00:07:16,110 --> 00:07:21,480 Be selected to receive an infusion of cash regularly should you meet some conditions. 81 00:07:21,480 --> 00:07:24,030 And that kind of gives us internal validity. 82 00:07:24,030 --> 00:07:26,670 That is what allows us to make a causal statement there. 83 00:07:26,670 --> 00:07:35,220 And what's very interesting about that is that we have five RCTs of conditional cash transfers in four different countries. 84 00:07:35,220 --> 00:07:36,720 So we have two in Mexico. 85 00:07:36,750 --> 00:07:40,680 We have one in the Philippines, one in Uganda, and the last one is in Nicaragua. 86 00:07:41,550 --> 00:07:43,200 JEREMY: Okay. So you've got these ... 87 00:07:43,200 --> 00:07:50,970 Effectively they're government programs usually where some people get a cash handout and other people ... 88 00:07:51,300 --> 00:07:53,880 I don't know whether they're actually randomized. 89 00:07:53,880 --> 00:07:59,720 You say they're randomized controlled trials, but there's a group of people who get the cash and a group of people who don't, and you can 90 00:07:59,720 --> 00:08:01,400 look at their expenditures. 91 00:08:01,400 --> 00:08:07,820 So what is the income elasticity of demand for food purchases? 92 00:08:08,120 --> 00:08:09,380 MARC: Well, it's positive. 93 00:08:09,380 --> 00:08:18,620 So in line with your intuition, as poor people get money and this is money that's given to them kind of in a random 94 00:08:18,620 --> 00:08:23,030 fashion, they can they take some of it and spend it on food. 95 00:08:23,030 --> 00:08:25,040 In other words, demand for food goes up. 96 00:08:25,100 --> 00:08:29,720 The interesting news is that it's not as much as people expected. 97 00:08:29,810 --> 00:08:35,450 Our estimates are lower than what the literature had hitherto presented. 98 00:08:36,740 --> 00:08:39,200 And that is an interesting fact. 99 00:08:39,200 --> 00:08:45,680 Or, that's an interesting result, because honestly, I was of the school of thought that, you know, you're going to see them very much 100 00:08:45,710 --> 00:08:49,760 an economist in that sense, but I was of the school of thought that income fixes everything. 101 00:08:50,240 --> 00:08:54,020 Money is the, you know, is the answer to a lot of problems. 102 00:08:54,500 --> 00:09:01,630 And so I thought, well, if we just give people more income, right, if as incomes go up, as the development process takes place, all of those 103 00:09:01,630 --> 00:09:07,390 nutrition issues are going to get resolved because people are just going to start upgrading what they consume, and they're going to be, 104 00:09:07,420 --> 00:09:09,460 you know, they're going to be better nourished. 105 00:09:09,460 --> 00:09:12,040 We're going to see fewer hungry people. 106 00:09:12,040 --> 00:09:19,240 So our income elasticity estimates are not as high as what most people kind of would have speculated up to now. 107 00:09:19,240 --> 00:09:23,170 And that was kind of a very sobering fact because it ... 108 00:09:23,200 --> 00:09:28,750 You know, sometimes you find a result that really changes how you view how the world works. 109 00:09:28,750 --> 00:09:29,920 And that is one of them. 110 00:09:29,920 --> 00:09:37,720 That is one of those things where I, you know, it hasn't happened frequently in the course of my research that I had a finding where I 111 00:09:37,720 --> 00:09:39,570 thought, this is entirely ... 112 00:09:39,570 --> 00:09:40,720 It's not entirely different, right? 113 00:09:40,750 --> 00:09:46,060 If it were entirely different, I would have found that giving people more money means that they spend less money on food. 114 00:09:46,060 --> 00:09:49,330 That is not what we find, but we find that they don't spend as much as what we expect. 115 00:09:49,330 --> 00:09:56,140 And thus the whole kind of income as solution to so many problems does not hold. 116 00:09:56,230 --> 00:09:57,430 JEREMY: Just to go back. 117 00:09:57,460 --> 00:10:04,960 You said that elasticity is great because it tells you how much does spending go up for a 1% increase in income. 118 00:10:04,960 --> 00:10:12,730 And naively, you might think 1% increase in income, 1% increase in in spending on food. 119 00:10:12,730 --> 00:10:16,570 So how much do they increase their spending on food. 120 00:10:16,990 --> 00:10:23,830 MARC: Yeah. So so what we do is we find an income elasticity for overall food expenditures of 0.03. 121 00:10:24,100 --> 00:10:25,900 It's about three cents on the dollar. 122 00:10:25,930 --> 00:10:27,580 JEREMY: That's really not very ... 123 00:10:28,240 --> 00:10:30,550 MARC: It is really not very much, exactly right. 124 00:10:30,580 --> 00:10:32,470 It is way less than you would expect. 125 00:10:32,470 --> 00:10:34,990 I mean, I would not expect a 1 to 1. 126 00:10:34,990 --> 00:10:42,190 I would not expect a one dollar on the dollar because we know that food is a necessity, which means or we know, we know from theory -- 127 00:10:42,220 --> 00:10:48,820 again, see, I'm taking theory a little bit too seriously -- what we know from theory is that food ought to be a necessity, meaning that 128 00:10:48,820 --> 00:10:52,150 the income elasticity of food ought to be less than one, for food overall. 129 00:10:52,570 --> 00:11:01,620 That is, for luxury goods, for stuff like caviar, we would expect the elasticity to be greater than one, because those are luxury goods or 130 00:11:01,620 --> 00:11:02,820 they're deemed to be luxury goods. 131 00:11:02,820 --> 00:11:11,520 But for food overall, we would expect it to be between 0 and 1, and we certainly find between 0 and 1, but we find it much closer to zero 132 00:11:11,550 --> 00:11:15,240 than than I expected going into this project. 133 00:11:15,330 --> 00:11:17,400 JEREMY: And it's also ... 134 00:11:17,430 --> 00:11:18,840 I mean, I have ... 135 00:11:18,870 --> 00:11:28,650 My expectation would be that it would be higher, especially because very often cash transfers are targeted at women because they're 136 00:11:28,650 --> 00:11:37,620 kind of responsible for feeding the family, and they're often accompanied by education on nutritional questions. 137 00:11:37,980 --> 00:11:45,660 So maybe that targeting is not necessary either. 138 00:11:46,680 --> 00:11:49,170 MARC: That is something we can't quite get into, right? 139 00:11:49,200 --> 00:11:52,470 We can't speak to the targeting of those cash transfers. 140 00:11:52,470 --> 00:11:56,750 What we have is this exogenous variation in who gets cash and who doesn't. 141 00:11:58,010 --> 00:12:05,930 I would like to clarify, too, that this is an intent to treat estimate, meaning that when we give people money, we can't force them 142 00:12:05,930 --> 00:12:07,760 to take it up and do stuff with it, right? 143 00:12:07,790 --> 00:12:14,840 So this is, we intend to treat those people or the people who ran those randomized control trials in the first place intended to treat 144 00:12:14,840 --> 00:12:16,490 the people who receive the cash. 145 00:12:16,520 --> 00:12:18,590 What they do with it is entirely up to them. 146 00:12:18,590 --> 00:12:22,250 So it's what we call in the literature an ITT estimate. 147 00:12:22,700 --> 00:12:24,890 That being said, Jeremy, I want to go back a step. 148 00:12:25,220 --> 00:12:29,840 What we find is, yes, overall for food, we find that it's 0.03. 149 00:12:29,840 --> 00:12:31,310 So three cents on the dollar. 150 00:12:31,880 --> 00:12:39,920 But of course staples, right, stuff again going back to like my definition of coarse versus fine stuff like sorghum and millet exhibit 151 00:12:39,920 --> 00:12:41,630 the most inelastic demand. 152 00:12:41,630 --> 00:12:49,460 And their estimated income elasticity is not statistically different from zero, meaning that for a change in income, we don't see people 153 00:12:49,460 --> 00:12:55,540 changing in a statistically meaningful fashion their expenditures on course staples. 154 00:12:55,870 --> 00:13:05,410 What has the highest -- which is in line with so many reports and so much of the conventional wisdom in this kind of economics 155 00:13:05,410 --> 00:13:11,980 of food demand and nutrition literature -- is that the most elastic demand is animal sourced protein. 156 00:13:12,640 --> 00:13:20,470 And so in that sense, we do find stuff that's in line with people's expectations of, yes, as people get these kind of as people get these 157 00:13:20,470 --> 00:13:26,350 random infusions of -- random across people, not over time -- they they will spend, you know ... 158 00:13:26,980 --> 00:13:33,370 The demand of food, sorry, the category of food that responds most to this influx of cash is animal source protein. 159 00:13:33,580 --> 00:13:38,080 JEREMY: So that's getting to Bennett's law or Bennett's Observational Regularity. 160 00:13:39,220 --> 00:13:40,390 MARC: Correct? Yeah. 161 00:13:40,480 --> 00:13:47,860 JEREMY: Can can you can you actually do the three steps, of course to fine staples and fine staples to meat? 162 00:13:47,860 --> 00:13:49,030 MARC: So you got us there. 163 00:13:49,030 --> 00:13:54,610 So, I am very, very happy to report that yes, we can get to those three steps. 164 00:13:54,640 --> 00:13:56,770 What I'm slightly less ... 165 00:13:57,790 --> 00:14:04,270 What I was kind of more surprised by, not disappointed necessarily, is that we find partial support for Bennett's Law. 166 00:14:04,600 --> 00:14:12,790 The average household in our, across our five contexts substitutes fine staples for coarse staples, substitutes protein for coarse 167 00:14:12,790 --> 00:14:16,630 staples, both of which are consistent with Bennett's Law. 168 00:14:16,630 --> 00:14:19,420 But you'll notice that there is a glaring omission, right? 169 00:14:19,450 --> 00:14:25,570 We don't find that they substitute protein for fine staples. 170 00:14:25,570 --> 00:14:33,760 So this is kind of like this middle step where people might, where you think, well, they would move away from rice and consume more 171 00:14:33,760 --> 00:14:35,800 chicken perhaps, or more fish. 172 00:14:35,800 --> 00:14:37,030 We don't see that step. 173 00:14:37,030 --> 00:14:46,420 What we do find is that people will substitute chicken and maybe pork and beef for sorghum and millet, and they substitute rice for sorghum 174 00:14:46,420 --> 00:14:50,180 and millet. But we don't find that middle step, which may just ... 175 00:14:50,180 --> 00:14:56,620 I mean, we don't know whether that's kind of a noise problem in the data, where, you know, it's the data are just a little bit too noisy 176 00:14:56,620 --> 00:15:01,450 to detect that. We find the right sign in that direction, but we just don't find significance, is what we find. 177 00:15:01,450 --> 00:15:03,280 But it is exciting. 178 00:15:03,310 --> 00:15:04,870 I mean, you know, I said I was disappointed. 179 00:15:04,870 --> 00:15:05,950 That is not entirely true. 180 00:15:05,980 --> 00:15:11,650 I mean, I'm very excited about providing the first credible test of Bennett's Law in the literature. 181 00:15:11,650 --> 00:15:15,220 It's something that's been kind of on my mind very much since I learned about it. 182 00:15:15,220 --> 00:15:16,780 I thought, this is fantastic. 183 00:15:16,810 --> 00:15:26,740 This is entirely true, entirely true based on my expectations or based on my intuition and the patterns that we observe in, kind of, in 184 00:15:26,740 --> 00:15:27,370 our lives. 185 00:15:27,400 --> 00:15:31,480 So if I, if I may just kind of a little personal aside. 186 00:15:33,730 --> 00:15:43,150 My parents, you know, you don't have to go very far up the family tree to find people who were living in rural areas of Quebec in 187 00:15:43,150 --> 00:15:46,390 poverty and people for whom even ... 188 00:15:46,420 --> 00:15:53,750 You know, if I talk to my mother, she will tell you that a meal is not a meal unless it's got starch. 189 00:15:53,750 --> 00:15:56,780 So a meal is not a meal if it doesn't have potatoes. 190 00:15:56,810 --> 00:16:01,160 A meal is not a meal if it doesn't have bread. 191 00:16:01,160 --> 00:16:08,240 And she will entertain the possibility of pasta and rice as well, which are not exactly endemic to French Canada, but she will entertain 192 00:16:08,240 --> 00:16:09,290 that possibility. 193 00:16:09,410 --> 00:16:16,250 And so these things don't change very quickly, I think, across generations, because of habit formation and the way we eat. 194 00:16:16,250 --> 00:16:24,260 And that might be something to look into, I think, as a next step of, sure, okay, you see that people themselves will change a little bit at 195 00:16:24,260 --> 00:16:27,920 the margin, but there's a lot of holdovers from history. 196 00:16:27,920 --> 00:16:34,760 There's a lot of holdovers from culture and from these are habits of consumption that are formed well in infancy. 197 00:16:34,790 --> 00:16:40,430 Right? I mean, you look at how people eat and they'll say, well, I've always eaten this way when I was little, and there's all kinds of 198 00:16:40,430 --> 00:16:50,330 emotions and kind of cultural baggage that is tied into that, and personal history that's tied into how people eat that demand might 199 00:16:50,330 --> 00:16:56,110 not switch as easily for food as it does, say, for VCRs or the type of computer that you're using. 200 00:16:56,560 --> 00:17:00,220 JEREMY: Maybe this is a digression, or maybe ... 201 00:17:00,820 --> 00:17:02,020 Well, if ... 202 00:17:02,050 --> 00:17:11,650 Is there a kind of inverse Bennett's Law that when people are rich and educated and have been for a while, 203 00:17:11,650 --> 00:17:20,500 they start eating lower, they start eating whole grains and less meat and quote unquote, healthy. 204 00:17:21,730 --> 00:17:23,560 MARC: That is a fantastic question. 205 00:17:23,560 --> 00:17:32,680 That is where my mind has been for, I would say, about ten years, because when I learned about Bennett's Law, yes, I thought, hey, you 206 00:17:32,680 --> 00:17:34,510 know, I've lived in Madagascar. 207 00:17:34,570 --> 00:17:42,370 I certainly have seen people in a cross section of Malagasy society, right, certainly eat lots and lots of rice at the low end of the 208 00:17:42,370 --> 00:17:45,040 income scale, eat a lot more meat. 209 00:17:45,040 --> 00:17:51,310 So the guys that I was working with, the enumerators that were working with me on my, on my survey when I did my dissertation 210 00:17:51,310 --> 00:17:54,880 fieldwork. They they loved meat, right? 211 00:17:55,480 --> 00:18:01,420 Whenever we would go out as a team and I was footing the bill, those guys would go all in on meat. 212 00:18:01,420 --> 00:18:04,990 And they were very happy to eat, you know, like more than rice and greens. 213 00:18:05,800 --> 00:18:07,480 So I've seen that. 214 00:18:07,510 --> 00:18:15,700 And, you know, we see it in our own experience and again, in a time series sense of my grandparents and my parents and the way they were 215 00:18:15,700 --> 00:18:16,990 raised and the way they eat. 216 00:18:17,500 --> 00:18:21,340 And so that I asked myself, okay, but this is very interesting. 217 00:18:21,340 --> 00:18:26,500 It tells us what happened in the past from a development sense, living in a high income country. 218 00:18:26,560 --> 00:18:28,480 But quo vadis, right? 219 00:18:28,510 --> 00:18:30,400 What am I looking at for the future? 220 00:18:30,400 --> 00:18:35,590 And so I've got an undergraduate student, a wonderfully talented young woman. 221 00:18:36,880 --> 00:18:43,000 And best of all, she is intellectually curious and she's driven, and she loves to think about food policy. 222 00:18:43,270 --> 00:18:51,780 But what she is doing is, using qualitative evidence to document what are the consumption patterns of people in this country, in the United 223 00:18:51,780 --> 00:18:53,790 States, across the income domain. 224 00:18:54,360 --> 00:19:02,700 And so my initial speculation -- and she she doesn't have very firm results yet -- we met yesterday for the, not for the first time, but 225 00:19:02,700 --> 00:19:05,040 for the first time she brought some qualitative results. 226 00:19:05,040 --> 00:19:11,880 But my expectation going in was exactly as you say, right as you get to a certain income level -- and sorry for this very roundabout 227 00:19:11,880 --> 00:19:19,320 answer, it took a while to get here -- but as you get to a certain income level, you start demanding different food. 228 00:19:19,350 --> 00:19:24,180 You start worrying about health aspects of the food you're consuming. 229 00:19:24,210 --> 00:19:29,820 Sure, Bennett's Law tells you that as you get rich, you're going to consume more animal sourced foods. 230 00:19:29,820 --> 00:19:34,980 And that's certainly true is true in what EEshani, Katherina, and I find in our paper. 231 00:19:35,760 --> 00:19:43,320 But if you look at the data in the United States, for instance, you see that people consume a lot more fish and seafood, a lot plant, a 232 00:19:43,320 --> 00:19:44,910 lot more plant derived protein. 233 00:19:44,940 --> 00:19:47,700 I mean, I am an example myself. 234 00:19:47,700 --> 00:19:53,660 A colleague is visiting here who is giving our Friday seminar and she is staying with us. 235 00:19:53,660 --> 00:19:56,870 And this morning I was making her coffee and I said, what do you want? 236 00:19:57,230 --> 00:20:05,420 We have regular milk, but we also have pea milk and almond milk because my wife likes to drink pea milk with her coffee and I drink 237 00:20:05,450 --> 00:20:11,780 almond milk, and we have dairy milk because that's what my daughter eats in her cereal and, you know, little kids should probably get 238 00:20:11,780 --> 00:20:15,920 dairy milk with all the enhancements and enrichments that it has. 239 00:20:15,920 --> 00:20:18,410 So yes, we certainly see that in the data, right? 240 00:20:18,440 --> 00:20:26,120 That as people get very wealthy, they will substitute away from this, away from kind of like straight up animal source protein and go 241 00:20:26,150 --> 00:20:31,010 towards vegetable or plant derived protein. 242 00:20:31,010 --> 00:20:35,690 And even within kind of animal source, they're going to look at fish and seafood more than anything. 243 00:20:35,690 --> 00:20:37,400 So you're entirely right. 244 00:20:37,430 --> 00:20:47,210 JEREMY: Okay. Going going back to the poorer people and their demand for meat and animal protein, if it's kind of, if 245 00:20:47,210 --> 00:20:56,830 it's lower than may be expected, does that mean that fears about the impact of demand for animal 246 00:20:56,830 --> 00:21:05,710 protein on greenhouse gas emissions-- so more livestock, more greenhouse gas emissions, more climate change -- are those fears then 247 00:21:05,740 --> 00:21:07,030 exaggerated? 248 00:21:09,220 --> 00:21:13,990 MARC: I hesitate to say that this is but one estimate. 249 00:21:14,560 --> 00:21:18,340 My sense if I were to go purely with our estimates, I would say yes. 250 00:21:18,340 --> 00:21:20,740 Maybe those fears are a little bit exaggerated. 251 00:21:20,770 --> 00:21:22,810 That doesn't mean that they're wrong, right? 252 00:21:22,840 --> 00:21:25,960 It just means that they are less than what we were expecting. 253 00:21:26,230 --> 00:21:35,890 That being said, the fact remains that income elasticity for a food demand for animal sourced foods remains 254 00:21:35,890 --> 00:21:45,070 positive. Which means that as countries that are on the lower to middle income scale develop, they are going to again, the sign is 255 00:21:45,070 --> 00:21:47,920 right, right? The sign is what people thought it was. 256 00:21:48,010 --> 00:21:55,060 And so as as the demand for food, as the demand for animal source protein goes up in low and middle income countries, something is going 257 00:21:55,060 --> 00:22:00,370 to have to give if we want -- with the goal of climate -- if we want to kind of hit those climate targets. 258 00:22:00,370 --> 00:22:10,090 And thus I think it is incumbent on high income countries to kind of examine their own consumption patterns, because where I have a 259 00:22:10,090 --> 00:22:18,190 problem as an economist and where I have a problem as a, you know, as a critical thinking citizen, is when I hear policymakers kind of look 260 00:22:18,220 --> 00:22:25,900 at those demand patterns and say, oh, well, people in low income countries are going to have to adjust their consumption and move away 261 00:22:25,900 --> 00:22:32,860 from ... And there are a lot of people like that who will kind of lecture low and middle income countries and say, oh, you got to, don't 262 00:22:32,860 --> 00:22:34,030 do what we did, right? 263 00:22:34,060 --> 00:22:43,690 Do as I say, not as I did, which I find very hypocritical because there comes a stage of development where we are not 264 00:22:43,720 --> 00:22:46,210 working in offices, typing on computers all day. 265 00:22:46,240 --> 00:22:54,420 Right? People do physical work in the manufacturing sector or stuff that's not necessarily a services sector, where you need you need to 266 00:22:54,450 --> 00:22:55,920 grow strong and tall. 267 00:22:55,920 --> 00:23:00,510 And the way you do that is by consuming enough animal source protein. 268 00:23:00,510 --> 00:23:06,930 I'm not a nutritionist, but from what I know, you can get enough protein from plant derived foods. 269 00:23:07,320 --> 00:23:17,280 But from what I know, you don't get the nine necessary amino acids in plant derived proteins the way you get them as easily available in 270 00:23:17,280 --> 00:23:26,190 animal source foods. And so to deny that to billions of people when you're sitting pretty here in your ivory tower, I find this a little 271 00:23:26,220 --> 00:23:31,350 bit, you know ... It's not, you know, it's not just wrongheaded, it's also hypocritical. 272 00:23:31,380 --> 00:23:40,950 JEREMY: Yeah. I mean, the Eat Lancet, the original Eat Lancet diet was a classic example of, oh, no, poor people mustn't eat meat. 273 00:23:41,490 --> 00:23:42,930 Nobody must eat meat. 274 00:23:42,960 --> 00:23:52,850 Anyway, leaving that aside, finally, in the paper, you actually say that increased income had a limited impact 275 00:23:52,850 --> 00:23:57,800 on food consumption and in turn, on nutritional well-being. 276 00:23:58,100 --> 00:24:07,160 But you also say that cash transfers are effective, and that's especially if you compare them to nutritional supplements and in-kind 277 00:24:07,190 --> 00:24:12,590 transfers. So, I'm a policy maker. 278 00:24:12,620 --> 00:24:14,960 What's your best advice? 279 00:24:17,870 --> 00:24:19,060 MARC: I think ... 280 00:24:19,060 --> 00:24:21,980 So my best advice would be do ... 281 00:24:21,980 --> 00:24:23,720 cash transfers are indeed effective right? 282 00:24:23,750 --> 00:24:26,000 They have, they hit several targets. 283 00:24:26,000 --> 00:24:29,540 We're looking at one slice of what those cash transfers do. 284 00:24:29,600 --> 00:24:32,150 And the good thing about cash transfers is that they're very straightforward. 285 00:24:33,140 --> 00:24:36,710 They are incredibly simple to administer. 286 00:24:36,950 --> 00:24:41,480 And so if you think about well what's cost effective, what's easy to do is ... 287 00:24:41,600 --> 00:24:44,810 Giving people cash is easy to do and then it gives them ... 288 00:24:44,810 --> 00:24:52,600 And this is where I may differ from many other policymakers or from many policymakers and other economists or other social scientists ... 289 00:24:52,600 --> 00:24:57,100 But I think when you give people cash, they will use it for what they think is best for them. 290 00:24:57,100 --> 00:25:03,700 And sure, you're going to have some collateral damage, like someone's going to use the cash to drink it, someone's going to use the cash 291 00:25:03,700 --> 00:25:08,740 for, you know, to buy cigarettes with it, to buy illicit drugs. 292 00:25:08,740 --> 00:25:10,270 That is not something you can fix. 293 00:25:10,270 --> 00:25:15,460 And that is something that, at any rate, as the development process occurs, you're going to see more and more of that. 294 00:25:15,460 --> 00:25:19,330 So I find the whole cash transfer argument to be very appealing. 295 00:25:19,330 --> 00:25:27,820 It's very administratively simple and it delivers results even if the results are more humble, even if, or even if the estimates of the 296 00:25:27,820 --> 00:25:32,350 effects are more sobering than what you thought going in, as I did with this paper. 297 00:25:33,070 --> 00:25:43,060 JEREMY: Marc Bellemare of the University of Minnesota, reaffirming the idea that giving poor people cash is a good idea, even if they don't 298 00:25:43,060 --> 00:25:46,780 spend quite as much of it on food as one might like. 299 00:25:47,860 --> 00:25:56,230 I'll put a link to the paper by Marc and his colleagues in the show notes at Eat This Podcast.com, along with some other links that you 300 00:25:56,230 --> 00:25:58,090 might find interesting. 301 00:25:59,800 --> 00:26:07,510 I hope you enjoyed this episode, and if you did, it would be great if you would tell a friend or even the world at large. 302 00:26:07,540 --> 00:26:14,080 Discovering new things to listen to remains the weakest link in independent podcasting. 303 00:26:14,080 --> 00:26:17,350 And by spreading the word, you can help. 304 00:26:17,650 --> 00:26:18,700 That's all for now. 305 00:26:18,730 --> 00:26:23,170 Don't forget, you can follow me and ask questions on Instagram and Mastodon. 306 00:26:24,010 --> 00:26:28,630 The links are on the website at Eat This podcast.com. 307 00:26:29,050 --> 00:26:41,200 So from me, Jeremy Cherfas and Eat This Podcast, goodbye and thanks for listening.